saucony是什么品牌| 上午8点是什么时辰| 甲状腺球蛋白低是什么意思| p波增宽是什么意思| 肝胆胰腺属于什么科| 吃香菜有什么好处| 开火上下结构念什么| 起死回生是什么意思| 什么东西能让皮肤变白| 肾结石可以喝什么饮料| 人体缺钙吃什么补最快| 绿豆和什么食物相克| 包干费用是什么意思| 先天性心脏病最怕什么| 小孩手足口病吃什么药| 尿酸高吃什么药降尿酸效果好| 糖化血红蛋白是什么| 伊丽莎白雅顿什么档次| 痛风石是什么| 毛囊炎用什么药最有效| 尿酸高是什么意思| 为什么拉肚子| 癸酉五行属什么| 百香果和什么不能一起吃| 什么叫安全期| 胃胀打嗝吃什么药最好| 右耳朵疼是什么原因| 51岁属什么| 山竹里面黄黄的是什么可以吃吗| 1和0是什么意思| 躯体形式障碍是什么病| 右耳鸣是什么原因| 路由器坏了有什么症状| 彩超检查什么| 脚褪皮是什么原因| 睡觉腿麻是什么原因引起| 什么是湿气重| 什么是脱敏| 胃不舒服吃什么| 女人吃善存有什么好处| 性出血是什么原因造成的呢要怎么办| 什么时候需要做肠镜| 妈妈的姐姐应该叫什么| 爸爸的爷爷叫什么| 体格检查是什么意思| 冠状沟有白色分泌物是什么原因| 一什么白菜| 天天都需要你爱是什么歌| 心率慢是什么原因| 睾丸痛吃什么消炎药| 青光眼用什么眼药水| 985和211有什么区别| 87年属于什么生肖| 文心什么字| 嗓子发炎挂什么科| 寒性和凉性有什么区别| 宫外孕什么意思| 4.11是什么星座| 心脏跳的快吃什么药| 高血压可以喝什么饮料| 小孩子注意力不集中是什么原因| 扩招是什么意思| ptc是什么意思| 大便为什么是绿色的| 四月十五什么星座| 出品人是干什么的| 点到为止是什么意思| 异地结婚登记需要什么证件| 右胸是什么器官| 膀胱壁毛糙是什么意思| 老九门2什么时候上映| 意中人是什么意思| 啾是什么意思| 全身皮肤瘙痒是什么原因| 吴优为什么叫大胸姐| 返祖现象什么意思| 6.28什么星座| 梦见小羊羔是什么意思| 谷丙转氨酶偏低是什么意思| 骂人是什么意思| 女性喝什么利尿最快| 胎位头位是什么意思| m蛋白是什么| 什么水果对胃好| 最近流行什么病毒| 胃疼胃胀用什么药效果最好| 寻麻疹看什么科| 什么食物含钙量最高| 看血管挂什么科| 崩溃是什么意思| 过继是什么意思| 夏天做什么菜| 玫瑰花茶和什么搭配好| 唐僧肉是什么意思| 寄居蟹吃什么食物| 炖鸡放什么材料| 错峰是什么意思| 十一月二十六是什么星座| 什么是子宫憩室| 1月1日是什么星座| rds是什么意思| 什么病会引起牙疼| 家里进鸟了是什么预兆| 拔牙之后可以吃什么| 孕吐吃什么可以缓解| sly是什么牌子| 开水冲服是什么意思| 骨龄是什么意思| 哈戳戳是什么意思| 中性粒细胞百分比高是什么原因| 神经痛什么原因引起的| 黄色配什么颜色最好看| 为什么狐臭女很漂亮| 感冒吃什么水果好得快| 单核细胞比率偏高说明什么| 猪拉稀用什么药最快| 日本投降是什么时候| 什么人不适合吃胃复春| 扯证是什么意思| 一片冰心在玉壶是什么意思| 胃寒吃什么食物暖胃| 宫颈ca什么意思| 羊齿状结晶代表什么| 肩周炎看什么科| 助听器什么牌子好| 女性分泌物像豆腐渣用什么药| 精湛是什么意思| 升读什么字| 手黄是什么原因| 北斗是什么| 变态是什么意思| 32周孕检检查什么项目| 肿瘤是什么病严重吗| 珠胎暗结是什么意思| 恶露后期为什么是臭的| pin是什么| 念珠菌是什么病| 禾加术念什么| 葛根是什么东西| 学架子鼓有什么好处| 匝道是什么| 氨基酸态氮是什么| 直肠壁增厚一般是什么情况| 结扎后需要注意什么| 孕激素是什么意思| 阿司匹林是什么| 纳闷是什么意思| 球蛋白偏高说明什么| 维生素e吃多了有什么副作用| 心率低40多吃什么药| 时光荏苒岁月如梭是什么意思| 因人而异是什么意思| 左眼跳什么右眼跳什么| 眼眶周围发黑什么原因| 吠陀是什么意思| 积劳成疾的疾什么意思| tct是什么意思| 红豆生南国什么意思| 深圳为什么叫鹏城| 婴儿足底采血查什么| 天津是什么省| 松脂是什么| 耐人寻味是什么意思| 隐士是什么意思| 心电图能检查出什么| 梦见手指流血是什么预兆| 太阳为什么能一直燃烧| 低筋面粉可以做什么| 双鱼座是什么星象| 孕妇牙痛有什么办法| 白蛋白下降是什么原因| 坐镇是什么意思| 仓鼠是什么动物| 指甲白色是什么原因| 96属什么生肖| 背痛是什么原因引起的| 什么气味能驱赶猫| 肝囊肿是什么原因造成的| 小妮子什么意思| 珑骧包属于什么档次| 苦笑是什么意思| 榕字五行属什么| 墓库是什么意思| 为什么想吐却吐不出来| 11月18号是什么星座的| 佛珠生菇讲述什么道理| 上什么下什么| 什么食物含磷高| 肾b超能检查出什么| act是什么意思| 评头论足什么意思| 胆固醇高有什么症状| verde是什么颜色| onlycook是什么牌子| 九牧王男装是什么档次| 独角仙吃什么食物| 下面痒是什么原因女性| 肚子疼吐了是什么原因| 颈椎ct能检查出什么| 刀代表什么数字| m的意思是什么| 一般什么原因做宫腔镜| 羊跟什么生肖最配| 越描越黑是什么意思| 鸡蛋和什么炒好吃| 子宫占位是什么意思| 解脲支原体阳性是什么意思| 城字五行属什么| 口琴买什么牌子好| 舀水是什么意思| 护士资格证什么时候考| 心脏不舒服挂什么科室| loft是什么意思| 狐仙一般找什么人上身| 尿检弱阳性是什么意思| 36属什么| 冰点脱毛的原理是什么| 脾不好吃什么药最见效| 胆小如鼠是什么生肖| 心电图hr是什么意思| 俄罗斯是什么国家| 甲硝唑有什么副作用| cop是什么| 存款到100万算什么阶层| 尿结石吃什么药| 男大三后面一句是什么| 吃干饭是什么意思| 手上的纹路代表什么| 榴莲为什么苦| 移居改姓始为良是什么意思| 后背酸痛是什么原因| 人为什么会失眠| 症瘕病是什么病| 无用功是什么意思| 扩词是什么| 关东八大碗都有什么| 傻白甜是什么意思| 出离心是什么意思| 一厢情愿是什么生肖| 含量是什么意思| 一花一世界一叶一菩提什么意思| 放疗期间吃什么食物最好| 不举什么意思| 乳腺囊性结节是什么意思| 水逆退散什么意思| 女人来月经有血块是什么原因| 铜镯子对人有什么好处| 九月十五日是什么星座| 夫复何求什么意思| 空气棉是什么面料| 剖腹产可以吃什么水果| 女孩断掌纹代表什么| 公举是什么意思啊| 爱奇艺积分有什么用| 再生障碍性贫血是什么病| 下葬下雨是什么兆头| 什么可以解酒最快方法| 13层楼房有什么说法吗| ri是什么意思| 跟腱为什么会断裂| 什么植物最好养| ipa是什么意思| aml是什么意思| pct是什么| 百度Jump to content

慈善公益对于乡村振兴至关重要

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
A Farm Security Administration photo of a cropper family chopping the weeds from cotton near White Plains, in Georgia, US (1941)
百度 二十四节气标示出的一年的气候变化,虽然对今天生活在城市的人来说不再是生产方面的指导性知识,但它仍然是中国人和自然之间漫长的农耕关系的续演,其中的传承意义深远。

Sharecropping is a legal arrangement in which a landowner allows a tenant (sharecropper) to use the land in return for a share of the crops produced on that land. Sharecropping is not to be conflated with tenant farming, which provides the tenant greater autonomy, and higher economic and social status.

Sharecropping has a long history and there are a wide range of different situations and types of agreements that have used a form of the system. Some are governed by tradition, and others by law. The French métayage, the Catalan masoveria, the Castilian mediero, the Slavic po?ownictwo and izdolshchina, the Italian mezzadria, and the Islamic system of muzara‘a (????????), are examples of legal systems that have supported sharecropping.

Overview

[edit]

Under a sharecropping system, landowners provided a share of land to be worked by the sharecropper, and usually provided other necessities such as housing, tools, seed, or working animals.[1] Local merchants usually provide food and other supplies to the sharecropper on credit. In exchange for the land and supplies, the cropper would pay the owner a share of the crop at the end of the season, typically one-half to two-thirds. The cropper used his share to pay off their debt to the merchant.[2] If there was any cash left over, the cropper kept it—but if their share came to less than what they owed, they remained in debt.

A new system of credit, the crop lien, became closely associated with sharecropping. Under this system, a planter or merchant extended a line of credit to the sharecropper while taking the year's crop as collateral. The sharecropper could then draw food and supplies all year long. When the crop was harvested, the planter or merchants who held the lien sold the harvest for the sharecropper and settled the debt.

Sociologist Jeffery M. Paige made a distinction between centralized sharecropping found on cotton plantations and the decentralized sharecropping with other crops. The former is characterized by long lasting tenure. Tenants are tied to the landlord through the plantation store. This form of tenure tends to be replaced by paid salaries as markets penetrate. Decentralized sharecropping involves virtually no role for the landlord: plots are scattered, peasants manage their own labor and the landowners do not manufacture the crops. This form of tenure becomes more common when markets penetrate.[3]

Farmers who farmed land belonging to others but owned their own mule and plow were called tenant farmers; they owed the landowner a smaller share of their crops, as the landowner did not have to provide them with as much in the way of supplies.

Application by region

[edit]

Historically, sharecropping occurred extensively in Scotland, Ireland and colonial Africa. Use of the sharecropper system has also been identified in England (as the practice of "farming to halves").[4] It was widely used in the Southern United States during the Reconstruction era (1865–1877) that followed the American Civil War, which was economically devastating to the Southern states.[5] It is still used in many rural poor areas of the world today, notably in Pakistan, India, and Bangladesh.[6][7][8]

Africa

[edit]

In settler colonies of colonial Africa, sharecropping was a feature of the agricultural life. White farmers, who owned most of the land, were frequently unable to work the whole of their farm for lack of capital. Therefore, they had African farmers to work the excess on a sharecropping basis.

In South Africa the 1913 Natives' Land Act[9] outlawed the ownership of land by Africans in areas designated for white ownership and effectively reduced the status of most sharecroppers to tenant farmers and then to farm laborers. In the 1960s, generous subsidies to white farmers meant that most farmers could afford to work their entire farms, and sharecropping faded out.

The arrangement has reappeared in other African countries in modern times, including Ghana[10] and Zimbabwe.[11]

Economic historian Pius S. Nyambara argued that Eurocentric historiographical devices such as "feudalism" or "slavery" often qualified by weak prefixes like "semi-" or "quasi-" are not helpful in understanding the antecedents and functions of sharecropping in Africa.[11]

United States

[edit]
Sharecroppers on the roadside after they were evicted for membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union (January 1936)

Prior to the Civil War, sharecropping is known to have existed in Mississippi and is believed to have been in place in Tennessee.[12][13] However, it was not until the economic upheaval caused by the American Civil War and the end of slavery during and after Reconstruction that it became widespread in the South.[14][5] It is theorized that sharecropping in the United States originated in the Natchez District, roughly centered in Adams County, Mississippi with its county seat, Natchez.[15]

After the war, plantations and other lands throughout the South were seized by the federal government. In January 1865, General William T. Sherman issued Special Field Orders No. 15, which announced that he would temporarily grant newly freed families 40 acres of this seized land on the islands and coastal regions of Georgia. Many believed that this policy would be extended to all former slaves and their families as repayment for their treatment at the end of the war. In the summer of 1865, President Andrew Johnson, as one of the first acts of Reconstruction, instead ordered all land under federal control be returned to the owners from whom it had been seized.

An early 20th century Texas sharecropper's home diorama at the Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum, in Greenville, Texas 2015

Southern landowners thus found themselves with a great deal of land but no liquid assets to pay for labor. They also maintained the "belief that gangs afforded the most efficient means of labor organization", something nearly all former slaves resisted. Preferring "to organize themselves into kin groups", as well as "minimize chances for white male-black female contact by removing their female kin from work environments supervised closely by whites", black southerners were "determined to resist the old slave ways".[16] Not with standing, many former slaves, now called freedmen, having no land or other assets of their own, needed to work to support their families. A sharecropping system centered on cotton, a major cash crop, developed as a result. Large plantations were subdivided into plots that could be worked by sharecroppers. Initially, sharecroppers in the American South were almost all formerly enslaved black people, but eventually cash-strapped indigent white farmers were integrated into the system.[2][17] During Reconstruction, the federal Freedmen's Bureau ordered the arrangements for freedmen and wrote and enforced their contracts.[18]

American sharecroppers worked a section of the plantation independently. In South Carolina, Georgia, Alabama and Mississippi, the dominant crop was usually cotton. In other areas it could be tobacco, rice, or sugar. At harvest time the crop was sold and the cropper received half of cash paid for the crop on his parcel.[19][20] Sharecroppers also often received their farming tools and all other goods from the landowner they were contracted with.[1] Landowners dictated decisions relating to the crop mix, and sharecroppers were often in agreements to sell their portion of the crop back to the landowner, thus being subjected to manipulated prices.[21] In addition to this, landowners, threatening to not renew the lease at the end of the growing season, were able to apply pressure to their tenants.[21] Sharecropping often proved economically problematic, as the landowners held significant economic control.[22]

Cotton sharecroppers, Hale County, Alabama, 1936

In the Reconstruction Era, sharecropping was one of few options for penniless freedmen to support themselves and their families. Other solutions included the crop-lien system (where the farmer was extended credit for seed and other supplies by the merchant), a rent labor system (where the farmer rents the land but keeps their entire crop), and the wage system (worker earns a fixed wage but keeps none of their crop). Sharecropping as historically practiced in the American South was more economically productive than the gang system plantations using slave labor, though less productive than modern agricultural techniques.[18][23]

Sharecropper's cabin displayed at Louisiana State Cotton Museum in Lake Providence, Louisiana (2013 photo)

Sharecropping continued to be a significant institution in many states for decades following the Civil War. By the early 1930s, there were 5.5 million white tenant farmers, sharecroppers, and mixed cropping/laborers in the United States; and 3 million Blacks.[24][25] In Tennessee, sharecroppers operated approximately one-third of all farm units in the state in the 1930s, with white people making up two thirds or more of the sharecroppers.[13] In Mississippi, by 1900, 36% of all white farmers were tenants or sharecroppers, while 85% of black farmers were.[12] In Georgia, fewer than 16,000 farms were operated by black owners in 1910, while, at the same time, African-Americans managed 106,738 farms as tenants.[26]

Around this time, sharecroppers began to form unions protesting against poor treatment, beginning in Tallapoosa County, Alabama in 1931 and Arkansas in 1934. Membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union included both blacks and poor whites, who used meetings, protests, and labor strikes to push for better treatment. The success of these actions frightened and enraged landlords, who responded with aggressive tactics.[27] Landless farmers who fought the sharecropping system were socially denounced, harassed by legal and illegal means, and physically attacked by officials, landlords' agents, or in extreme cases, angry mobs.[28] Sharecroppers' strikes in Arkansas and the Missouri Bootheel, the 1939 Missouri Sharecroppers' Strike, were documented in the newsreel Oh Freedom After While.[29] The plight of a sharecropper was addressed in the song Sharecropper's Blues, recorded by Charlie Barnet and His Orchestra in 1944.[30]

Sharecroppers' chapel at Cotton Museum in Lake Providence

The sharecropping system in the U.S. increased during the Great Depression with the creation of tenant farmers following the failure of many small farms throughout the Dustbowl. Traditional sharecropping declined after mechanization of farm work became economical beginning in the late 1930s and early 1940s.[13][31] As a result, many sharecroppers were forced off the farms, and migrated to cities to work in factories, or became migrant workers in the Western United States during World War II. By the end of the 1960s, sharecropping had disappeared in the United States.[citation needed]

Sharecropping and socioeconomic status

[edit]
White sharecropper, J. B. Reeves, in Tomball, Texas.

About two-thirds of sharecroppers were white, the rest black. Sharecroppers, the poorest of the poor, organized for better conditions. The racially integrated Southern Tenant Farmers Union made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s. Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression, farm mechanization, and other factors.[32]

Impacts

[edit]

Sharecropping may have been harmful to tenants, with many cases of high interest rates, unpredictable harvests, and unscrupulous landlords and merchants often keeping tenant farm families severely indebted. The debt was often compounded year on year leaving the cropper vulnerable to intimidation and shortchanging.[33] Nevertheless, it appeared to be inevitable, with no serious alternative unless the croppers left agriculture.[34][35]

Landlords opt for sharecropping to avoid the administrative costs and shirking that occurs on plantations and haciendas. It is preferred to cash tenancy because cash tenants take all the risks, and any harvest failure will hurt them and not the landlord. Therefore, they tend to demand lower rents than sharecroppers.[36]

Some economists have argued that sharecropping is not as exploitative as it is often perceived. John Heath and Hans P. Binswanger write that "evidence from around the world suggests that sharecropping is often a way for differently endowed enterprises to pool resources to mutual benefit, overcoming credit restraints and helping to manage risk."[37]

Sharecropping agreements can be made fairly, as a form of tenant farming or sharefarming that has a variable rental payment, paid in arrears. There are three different types of contracts.[38]

  1. Workers can rent plots of land from the owner for a certain sum and keep the whole crop.
  2. Workers work on the land and earn a fixed wage from the land owner but keep some of the crop.
  3. No money changes hands but the worker and land owner each keep a share of the crop.

According to sociologist Edward Royce, "adherents of the neoclassical approach" argued that sharecropping incentivized laborers by giving them a vested interest in the crop. American plantations were wary of this interest, as they felt that would lead to African Americans demanding rights of partnership. Many black laborers denied the unilateral authority that landowners hoped to achieve, further complicating relations between landowners and sharecroppers.[21]

Sharecropping may allow women to have access to arable land, albeit not as owners, in places where ownership rights are vested only in men.[39]

Economic theories of share tenancy

[edit]
A sharecropper family in Walker County, Alabama (c. 1937)

The theory of share tenancy was long dominated by Alfred Marshall's famous footnote in Book VI, Chapter X.14 of Principles[40] where he illustrated the inefficiency of agricultural share-contracting. Steven N.S. Cheung (1969),[41] challenged this view, showing that with sufficient competition and in the absence of transaction costs, share tenancy will be equivalent to competitive labor markets and therefore efficient.[42]

He also showed that in the presence of transaction costs, share-contracting may be preferred to either wage contracts or rent contracts—due to the mitigation of labor shirking and the provision of risk sharing. Joseph Stiglitz (1974,[43] 1988),[44] suggested that if share tenancy is only a labor contract, then it is only pairwise-efficient and that land-to-the-tiller reform would improve social efficiency by removing the necessity for labor contracts in the first place.

Reid (1973),[45] Murrel (1983),[46] Roumasset (1995)[47] and Allen and Lueck (2004)[48] provided transaction cost theories of share-contracting, wherein tenancy is more of a partnership than a labor contract and both landlord and tenant provide multiple inputs. It has also been argued that the sharecropping institution can be explained by factors such as informational asymmetry (Hallagan, 1978;[49] Allen, 1982;[50] Muthoo, 1998),[51] moral hazard (Reid, 1976;[52] Eswaran and Kotwal, 1985;[53] Ghatak and Pandey, 2000),[54] intertemporal discounting (Roy and Serfes, 2001),[55] price fluctuations (Sen, 2011)[56] or limited liability (Shetty, 1988;[57] Basu, 1992;[58] Sengupta, 1997;[59] Ray and Singh, 2001).[60]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ a b Mandle, Jay R. Not Slave, Not Free: The African American Economic Experience Since the Civil War. Duke University Press, 1992, 22.
  2. ^ a b Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" The Journal of Negro History, Vol. 62, No.1 (January 1977), pp. 60–80 in JSTOR
  3. ^ Jeffery Paige, Agrarian Revolution, page 373
  4. ^ Griffiths, Liz Farming to Halves: A New Perspective on an Absurd and Miserable System in Rural History Today, Issue 6:2004 p.5, accessed at British Agricultural History Society, 16 February 2013.
  5. ^ a b Joseph D. Reid, "Sharecropping as an understandable market response: The postbellum South." Journal of Economic History (1973) 33#1 pp. 106–130. in JSTOR
  6. ^ Sanval, Nasim; Steven, Helfand (2025-08-07). Optimal groundwater management in Pakistan's Indus Water Basin. Intl Food Policy Res Inst.
  7. ^ Chaudhuri, Ananish; Maitra, Pushkar (2025-08-07). "Sharecropping contracts in rural India: A note". Journal of Contemporary Asia. 30 (1): 99–107. doi:10.1080/00472330080000071. ISSN 0047-2336. S2CID 154416728.
  8. ^ Byres, T. J. (2025-08-07). Sharecropping and Sharecroppers. Routledge. ISBN 978-1-135-78003-6.
  9. ^ "The Native Land Act is passed | South African History Online". Sahistory.org.za. Archived from the original on 14 October 2010. Retrieved 22 October 2023.
  10. ^ Leonard, R. and Longbottom, J., Land Tenure Lexicon: A glossary of terms from English and French speaking West Africa International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), London, 2000
  11. ^ a b Pius S. Nyambara (2003). "Rural Landlords, Rural Tenants, and the Sharecropping Complex in Gokwe, Northwestern Zimbabwe, 1980s–2002" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2025-08-07. Retrieved 2025-08-07., Centre for Applied Social Sciences, University of Zimbabwe and Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin–Madison, March 2003 (200Kb PDF)
  12. ^ a b Charles Bolton, "Farmers Without Land: The Plight of White Tenant Farmers and Sharecroppers Archived 2025-08-07 at the Wayback Machine", Mississippi History Now, March 2004.
  13. ^ a b c Robert Tracy McKenzie, "Sharecropping", Tennessee Encyclopedia of History and Culture.
  14. ^ Sharon Monteith, ed. (2013). The Cambridge Companion to the Literature of the American South. Cambridge U.P. p. 94. ISBN 9781107036789.
  15. ^ Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" The Journal of Negro History, Vol. 62, No.1 (January, 1977), pp. 60–80 in JSTOR
  16. ^ Jones, Jaqueline. Labor of Love, Labor of Sorrow: Black Women, Work, and the Family from Slavery to the Present. Basic Books, 1985.
  17. ^ Eva O'Donovan, Becoming Free in the Cotton South (2007); Gavin Wright, Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy Since the Civil War (1986); Roger L. Ransom and David Beckham, One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation (2nd ed. 2008)
  18. ^ a b Gregorie, Anne King (1954). History of Sumter County, South Carolina, p. 274. Library Board of Sumter County.
  19. ^ Woodman, Harold D. (1995). New South – New Law: The legal foundations of credit and labor relations in the Postbellum agricultural South. Louisiana State University Press. ISBN 0-8071-1941-5.
  20. ^ F. N. Boney (2025-08-07). "Poor Whites". The New Georgia Encyclopedia. Archived from the original on 2025-08-07. Retrieved 2025-08-07.
  21. ^ a b c Royce, Edward (1993). "The Rise of Southern Sharecropping". In Royce, Edward (ed.). The Origins of Southern Sharecropping. Temple University Press. pp. 181–222. ISBN 9781566390699. JSTOR j.ctt14bt3nz.9.
  22. ^ Ransom, Roger L., and Richard Sutch. One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation. 2nd edition. Cambridge England?; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001, 149.
  23. ^ Larry J. Griffin; Don Harrison Doyle (1995). The South As an American Problem. U. of Georgia Press. p. 168. ISBN 9780820317526.
  24. ^ The Rockabilly Legends; They Called It Rockabilly Long Before they Called It Rock and Roll by Jerry Naylor and Steve Halliday DVD
  25. ^ The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 184. ISBN 0-306-80743-2, ISBN 978-0-306-80743-5
  26. ^ Geisen, James C. (January 26, 2007). "Sharecropping". New Georgia Encyclopedia. Retrieved April 23, 2019.
  27. ^ The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 185. ISBN 0-306-80743-2, ISBN 978-0-306-80743-5
  28. ^ Sharecroppers All. Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid. Chapell Hill 1941. The University of North Carolina Press, 2011, ISBN 978-0-8078-9817-8
  29. ^ "California Newsreel - Film and Video for Social Change Since 1968". Newsreel.org. Retrieved 22 October 2023.
  30. ^ Charlie Barnet - Sharecropper's Blues. YouTube. 26 August 2011. Archived from the original on 2025-08-07.
  31. ^ Gordon Marshall, "Sharecropping," Encyclopedia.com, 1998.
  32. ^ "Sharecropping". Slavery by Another Name. PBS. Retrieved 7 December 2021.
  33. ^ "Sharecropping | Slavery By Another Name Bento". Sharecropping | Slavery By Another Name Bento | PBS.
  34. ^ Rufus B. Spain (1967). At Ease in Zion: Social History of Southern Baptists, 1865-1900. University of Alabama Press. p. 130. ISBN 9780817350383.
  35. ^ Johnny E. Williams (2008). African American Religion and the Civil Rights Movement in Arkansas. Univ. Press of Mississippi. p. 73. ISBN 9781604731866.
  36. ^ Sharecropping and Sharecroppers, T J Byres
  37. ^ Heath, John & Binswanger, Hans P. (October 1998). "Chapter 3: Policy-Induced Effects of Natural Resource Degradation: The Case of Colombia" (PDF). In Lutz, Ernest (ed.). Agriculture and the Environment: Perspectives on Sustainable Rural Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank. pp. 32. ISBN 0-8213-4249-5. Retrieved 2025-08-07.
  38. ^ Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid, Sharecroppers All (1941); Gavin Wright, Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy since the Civil War (1986).
  39. ^ Bruce, John W.- Country Profiles of Land Tenure: Africa, 1996 (Lesotho, p. 221) Research Paper No. 130, December 1998, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin-Madison accessed at UMN.edu Archived 2025-08-07 at the Wayback Machine June 19, 2006
  40. ^ Alfred Marshall (1920). Principles of Economics (8th ed.). London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd.
  41. ^ Cheung, Steven N S (1969). "Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements". Journal of Law & Economics. 12 (1): 23–42. doi:10.1086/466658. S2CID 154860968. Retrieved 2025-08-07.
  42. ^ Formalized in Roumasset, James (1979). "Sharecropping, Production Externalities and the Theory of Contracts". American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 61 (4): 640–647. doi:10.2307/1239911. JSTOR 1239911.
  43. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (1974). "Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping" (PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 41 (2): 219–255 j. doi:10.2307/2296714. JSTOR 2296714. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2025-08-07. Retrieved 2025-08-07.
  44. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (1988). "Principal And Agent". Princeton, Woodrow Wilson School – Discussion Paper (12). Retrieved 2025-08-07.
  45. ^ Reid, Joseph D. Jr. (March 1973). "Sharecropping As An Understandable Market Response: The Post-Bellum South". The Journal of Economic History. 33 (1): 106–130. doi:10.1017/S0022050700076476. JSTOR 2117145. S2CID 155056632.
  46. ^ Murrell, Peter (Spring 1983). "The Economics of Sharing: A Transactions Cost Analysis of Contractual Choice in Farming". The Bell Journal of Economics. 14 (1): 283–293. doi:10.2307/3003555. JSTOR 3003555.
  47. ^ Roumasset, James (March 1995). "The nature of the agricultural firm". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 26 (2): 161–177. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(94)00007-2.
  48. ^ Allen, Douglas W.; Dean Lueck (2004). The Nature of the Farm: Contracts, Risk, and Organization in Agriculture. MIT Press. p. 258. ISBN 9780262511858.
  49. ^ Hallagan, William (1978). "Self-selection by contractual choice and the theory of sharecropping". Bell Journal of Economics. 9 (2): 344–354. doi:10.2307/3003586. JSTOR 3003586.
  50. ^ Allen, Franklin (1982). "On share contracts and screening". Bell Journal of Economics. 13 (2): 541–547. doi:10.2307/3003473. JSTOR 3003473.
  51. ^ Muthoo, Abhinay (1998). "Renegotiation-proof tenurial contracts as screening mechanisms". Journal of Development Economics. 56: 1–26. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(98)00050-9.
  52. ^ Reid, Joseph D. Jr. (1976). "Sharecropping and agricultural uncertainty". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 24 (3): 549–576. doi:10.1086/450897. JSTOR 1153005. S2CID 154402121.
  53. ^ Eswaran, Mukesh; Ashok Kotwal (1985). "A theory of contractual structure in agriculture". American Economic Review. 75 (3): 352–367. JSTOR 1814805.
  54. ^ Ghatak, Maitreesh; Priyanka Pandey (2000). "Contract choice in agriculture with joint moral hazard in effort and risk". Journal of Development Economics. 63 (2): 303–326. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00116-4.
  55. ^ Roy, Jaideep; Konstantinos Serfes (2001). "Intertemporal discounting and tenurial contracts". Journal of Development Economics. 64 (2): 417–436. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00144-9.
  56. ^ Sen, Debapriya (2011). "A theory of sharecropping: the role of price behavior and imperfect competition" (PDF). Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 80 (1): 181–199. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2011.03.006. S2CID 191253.
  57. ^ Shetty, Sudhir (1988). "Limited liability, wealth differences, and the tenancy ladder in agrarian economies". Journal of Development Economics. 29: 1–22. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(88)90068-5.
  58. ^ Basu, Kaushik (1992). "Limited liability and the existence of share tenancy" (PDF). Journal of Development Economics. 38: 203–220. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(92)90026-6.
  59. ^ Sengupta, Kunal (1997). "Limited liability, moral hazard and share tenancy". Journal of Development Economics. 52 (2): 393–407. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(96)00444-0.
  60. ^ Ray, Tridip; Nirvikar Singh (2001). "Limited liability, contractual choice and the tenancy ladder". Journal of Development Economics. 66: 289–303. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(01)00163-8.

Further reading

[edit]
[edit]
眼睛总是干涩是什么原因 大便出血吃什么药 梦见发洪水是什么征兆 打更是什么意思 猫咪能吃什么水果
内分泌失调吃什么调理 梦见掉牙齿是什么征兆 前囟门什么时候闭合 众矢之地是什么意思 豆五行属什么
溺爱什么意思 刚愎自用代表什么生肖 口腔溃疡用什么药 一直呕吐是什么原因 镇长属于什么级别
尿液很黄是什么原因 熟络是什么意思 什么是脑卒中 3月10日是什么星座 不适随诊是什么意思
甸是什么意思hcv7jop5ns5r.cn 血压表什么牌子的好最准确最耐用hcv9jop8ns3r.cn 20至30元什么烟最好抽hcv7jop6ns3r.cn 操刀是什么意思hcv9jop7ns4r.cn 放大镜不能放大的东西是什么hcv8jop7ns3r.cn
cpi下降意味着什么hcv8jop6ns1r.cn 气是什么意思hcv7jop6ns1r.cn 买什么样的老花镜好jingluanji.com 吃杏有什么好处hcv8jop7ns9r.cn 立冬是什么时候xscnpatent.com
菠菜和豆腐为什么不能一起吃hcv8jop0ns5r.cn 被艹是什么感觉hcv8jop2ns6r.cn 瘘是什么意思hcv8jop9ns8r.cn 利福喷丁和利福平有什么区别hcv9jop0ns3r.cn 德国是什么民族hcv9jop0ns6r.cn
柠檬黄配什么颜色好看hcv8jop5ns0r.cn 什么食物含钾高hcv8jop0ns7r.cn 马女和什么属相最配yanzhenzixun.com 乳蛾是什么意思hcv9jop7ns9r.cn 买手机上什么网hcv8jop0ns7r.cn
百度